The next crisis could come from anywhere

SINCE its earliest days, the United States has suffered periodic financial crises. The first dates to 1792. In the 19th century, bank panics occurred regularly. Then, of course, came the great stockmarket crash of 1929 and the failure of two-fifths of the nation's banks in the Great Depression. Now we're in the midst of another crisis. It would be reassuring to think that the Obama administration's financial 'reforms' - or, indeed, any conceivable alternative - would prevent these collapses for all time. Dream on.

Every financial crisis originates in a failure of imagination. It's not that, before the crisis, no one foresees problems, 'excesses' and losses. There are usually warnings. But what's routinely overlooked is the fatal interconnections that transform problems into panic. People panic because the future goes dark. They don't know what to expect, and so they expect the worst. Markets cascade uncontrollably downwards.

The present crisis did not occur merely because 'sub-prime' mortgages experienced unexpectedly large losses or even because many of these loans were 'securitised' in complex bonds, argues Yale economist Gary Gorton. The crux of the matter, he says, was the failure of the 'repo' market. The term comes from 'repurchase agreements' - short-term loans (usually overnight) that require the borrower to pledge collateral (usually bonds) in return for cash; the collateral is then 'repurchased' by repayment of the loan. No one knows the size of the repo market; Mr Gorton thinks perhaps US$10 trillion at any moment. Banks relied heavily on repo loans, which were routinely renewed. But when doubts arose about banks' sub-prime securities, the repo market panicked. Loans vanished or became costlier. Deprived of credit, Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers failed; other institutions were vulnerable. Hardly anyone expected the panic; once it happened, large - but bearable - losses became a crisis.

In a crisis, government is the last bulwark against a complete financial collapse. That's the main justification for regulation. Just because all crises can't be prevented doesn't mean that some can't. Though complex, the Obama plan would essentially broaden regulation in three ways. First, it would empower the Federal Reserve to designate some financial institutions as so important that their failure would 'pose a threat to financial stability'. These institutions would face stiffer capital requirements - capital being mainly shareholders' investment. More capital would provide a larger buffer against losses and a crisis.

Second, it would create a Consumer Financial Protection Agency to police unethical lending practices and to ensure loan documents for mortgages, auto loans and other types of consumer credit are understandable. (The Securities and Exchange Commission would retain power over stock markets.) Third, it would change some rules of financial markets. For example, financial firms issuing securitised bonds would have to hold 5 per cent of the bonds themselves. By keeping some bonds, it's argued, sellers would scrutinise the underlying loans more carefully.

Though these proposals sound sensible, they have potential drawbacks. Writing in The Wall Street Journal, Peter Wallison of the American Enterprise Institute argued that the very largest financial institutions would become the protected and pampered wards of the state. 'Larger firms will squeeze out smaller ones,' he said. Consumer regulation sounds great. But if the protections are cumbersome and expensive, consumer credit will, paradoxically, become costlier. Lenders will compensate by raising interest rates or lending only to the safest borrowers.

Up to a point, some retrenchment of the financial sector is healthy. It absorbed too much of America's talent while pursuing strategies that, with hindsight, misallocated the nation's investment capital. But there are perils to over-regulation; it could dampen the normal risk-taking required for solid economic expansion.

However the debate concludes, regulation isn't a panacea against future crises. The idea of 'enlightened regulators' who are vastly more perceptive than the bankers, traders and money managers they regulate is a fiction. Even in early 2007, when the problems of sub-prime mortgages had emerged, few regulators or economists anticipated a wider financial meltdown. They didn't see the impending chain reaction. The problem wasn't a lack of regulation; it was a lack of imagination.

So the next crisis could come from anywhere - perhaps the follies of government, not finance. Between now and 2019, the US federal debt could rise US$11 trillion, projects the Congressional Budget Office. American Treasury bonds are the bedrock of the global financial system; they're considered safe and reliable. What if a glut of bonds causes investors to lose faith? What are the implications? Good questions. The seeds of the next crisis almost certainly won't be found in the debris of the last. -- The Washington Post Writers Group

Comments

Popular posts from this blog

I'm an accountant, I hate my job, but seriously, I wouldn’t know what else to do

Three money managers who lived through the 1987 stock-market crash warn of danger today

Have We Reached a Top?